Sunday, February 3, 2019

Colonialism and Decolonialization

For much of human history, there was not much difference in the development rates among peoples in different geographies. The Neolithic Revolution came to the Americas and Africa and Middle East and the Yellow River Delta, and people farmed their plot of land for their three score and ten and died without much contact from people who did not look like them unless you lived in a city on a trade route or a port, and even then this was limited compared to what came later. What then happened, was that some people got a hold of gunpowder and some boats and the idea that whatever they saw was by rights theirs because they were graced by God with the divine right to expand wherever their boats led them. These were mostly short white men without any special talent other than that gunpowders and those boats — except some novel pathogens that wreaked havoc on the newly-rediscovered-by-Europeans “New World” starting around 1493. There was also a transfer to a commodity form of production highlighted by mechanization and division of labor with wage workers that we know as “Capitalism” which gave those men in boats the resources to go to those countries and plant a flag (Cypher 83–4).

This adventuring overseas was good for a lot of people. Especially it was good for a lot of the white men with European Tongues who were able to claim the spoils of the adventuring. The negative effects were found on both sides of the ocean. If you open any page of a history like Galeano’s Open Veins of Latin America, you can find any number of horror stories like how “more than half the population of America, Australia, and Oceania died from the contamination of the first contact with white men” (18), or how conquistadors “killed so many Indians that it made a river of blood which is called the Olimtepeque” (19). On the other side of the Atlantic, observers like Engels in his The Conditions of the Working Class in England could see cities built with “cattle sheds for human beings” (63) where “it often happens that a whole Irish family is crowded into one bed” (77).
Colonialism is not just a problem during the time that western countries were in formal administration of nations that they held under its sway. Colonialism became a problem as these western nations wiped their hands clean of these nations. In fact, one of the common threads of today’s less developed countries today is that in the past they were under sway of colonial powers. This means that there is a lasting negative legacy as Cypher notes, “The good of the native peoples of the colonies was of little concern to the colonizers, except in so far as they might best serve to the advantage of the colonizer” (85). The structure on how the colonizing nations shaped the institutions and the physical infrastructure were such that they could maximize the extractive forces over the nations that they had control over and neglected long term regional cooperation amongst neighbor nations.

One example of the long-term problems was the lack of development of industry. As we saw above, part of the reason the Spanish went to Spain was to draw out the riches from the mountains of the New World. Part of the reason the British went to India was to gain their raw materials. In the Spanish case, there were no incentives to develop manufacturing as the Spanish were wholly extractive. Not just in the minerals from the mountains, but also in taking up the people who lived in the areas and putting them to work — making the workers abandon even agriculture so that they could go into the mines and pull silver or poison themselves with mercury as they reduced the ore to its pure state. In the British case, there was an existent Indian industrial base that was in existence, but they took tax and industrial policy and made the Indian peoples convert to raw material producers. By either discouraging or destroying the manufacturing base, the colonial powers made sure that these countries were low on the value chain and made it harder for them to move up. This is an example of path dependence, where “Once institutions have been formed, they tend to lock in a certain evolutionary path for the nation” (Cypher 87). The path dependency is part of why it makes it so much harder to evolve, because there is also a path dependency higher up the value chain, blocking a move for many of these countries.

It is not just the broader priorities that mattered how the colonial regimes shaped the current less developed nations. The legacy of colonialism strikes in how the physical world is built. The geographies are such that often the colonies are built for extraction. Here the example would be cities like Lagos or Kinshasa, built on the coast or a river where the transportation in and out is easy for the colonial powers. But this is not just a colonial issue. London on the Thames or Lisbon on the Tagus have the same general structure of the biggest city in the area being easy to get to. In a lot of ways geography is destiny. What was different with colonial build out was focused on making roads and railroads that could “convert resources into plantation lands and mines” (Cypher 101), bringing resources of a nation into the tradeable economy. And of course, these roads were not just built. Every mile of railroad was paved in bones and blood of the native people, with mortality rates of 25% a year on the work gangs (101). Finally, after all this building, there was only real one-way transportation. It was not about building trade within continents, but from the colony to metropole. This again created path dependence and evolution issues since the colonized world was split between a dozen powers, none of whom had the incentive to work on cross-colony trade and developing those links.

Finally, there were some factors holding down development in the post-colonial world that is not directly applicable to mendacious colonizers. The first would be the relative price of goods from the developing world compared to manufactured products. As the developed world improved their manufacturing productivity in relation to the lower productivity of the agricultural sectors, the relative value of the goods went up for the developing world and down for the developed world. This meant that there was less incentive to try to create a manufacturing base as the goods were importable. The incentive was to try to commit more land to agriculture or find more mines for raw materials (Cypher 102–3). This narrowed the focus of the countries until their economies were dominated one good. Having a strong mono-focused economy is fine just up until the point it is not anymore, if your good goes out of style or there is a less expensive source for it, or there are larger geopolitical issues and the United States decides it wants your oil. Looking at this monoculture though, it is easy to forget that there was only spotty coverage of the European occupation, stuck close to the shores and where they could control. There were a lot of places where there was still untouched subsistence agriculture, in a bifurcation of the economy called “economic dualism” which is the “clashing of an imported social system with an indigenous social system of another style. Most frequently, the imported social system is high capitalism” (Boeke qtd in Cypher 112). This dualism has been a barrier to integration of both the economic and political systems in a post-colonial age.

What we have seen in this essay is the move from colonialism to the challenges that colonialism created while it was in effect for the post-colonial world. In many ways, these were the result of structures put in place by the colonial powers, but others were the structure of market forces not in direct control of the colonizers. Either way, the structures and institutions put in place during colonialism set the countries on a harder path than they would have faced had they been allowed to develop by their selves. A broader question, not answered, is if capitalism could have been able to develop without imperialism.

Works Cited

Cypher, J. M. (2014). The process of economic development. London: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group.
Belfrage, C., & Galeano, E. H. (1997). Open Veins of Latin America: Five Centuries of the Pillage of a Continent. Monthly Review Foundation Incorporated.
Engels, F., & McLellan, D. (2009). The condition of the working class in England. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Monday, January 28, 2019

For Fewer Metrics

In “The Concept of Development,” Amartya Sen looks as economics as being closely related to development economics For Sen, these founders were motivated by development, as is he. The economic concern is “judged ultimately in terms of what it does to the lives of human beings” (Sen 11). The whole point of studying economics is to look at how to improve people’s lives.

The question then becomes how we improve people’s lives. It is one thing to talk about improvement in the abstract, but there are real concrete things that we can do, quantifications of things we can measure in terms of well-being, that show that we have moved people from a state of x to a state of x +1. The simplest of these is looking at the GDP or GNP in country specific terms. But just growing the gross output is not enough — as Sen states, “The relationship between GNP and living conditions is far from simple” (12). Sen moves beyond this structure noting the importance to look at “the nature of the life that people succeed in living” (Sen 15). To do this, one issue that Sen emphasizes is the “Freedom to Choose”. In this freedom, he defines as having “significant options,” so that “Being able to freely chose to lead a particular life may be a point of richer descriptions of the life we lead, including the choices we are able to make” (Sen 17). And the capability then is the set of alternatives with which a person must choose from.

In making this distinction, Sen looks at the difference from negative and positive freedoms. He notes that the freedom to be able to fast is much different from the freedom from starvation (18). In laying out the options, we have these broad possibilities of what could happen. I feel there is a bit of a problem with this approach in terms of how other people view it and how you craft it as a narrative in order to sell development to different audience.

Sen himself recognizes the problem with using a function and capabilities framework in that it “specifies a space in which evaluation is to take place, rather than proposing one particular formula for evaluation” (18), as well as calling for a “great deal of empirical as well as theoretical work” (19) to be done if this approach is taken. I fell that the problem is that we might not be ready for it. Already in terms of reading about the different metrics we have for looking at development and access to resources and how that is spread in a country there are a multiplicity of them. And these are metrics that have been taken and organized and made available on the World Bank website and then it hides there, waiting for enthuastic amateurs and trained professionals to access.

The problem is that though we have these numbers available, we tend to think in stories. I’m thinking of being a citizen in the developed west and feeling that there is a moral obligation to make sure that people in developing countries have access to running water and chlorine and mosquito nets and freedom from sexual violence. These are things that I would assume that most people would support in the abstract. We get to an issue when we then we must sell outside investment through the international organizations to taxpayers and politicians in the developed world. We have a world where when polled people will say that 25% of the US budget goes to foreign aid, when it is less than one percent. People’s perceptions are very narrow and parochial, so that though I can appreciate Sen’s approach, it’s too broad.

In “Mismeasuring Our Lives”, Sen and co-authors argue for a dashboard approach instead of just relying on GDP as the singular measure of well-being. The problem with that, as well as the functions and capabilities approach to development is that Americans thrive on stories and simplicity and not nuance. For example, recently with the large stock market moves in December, people had a hard time understanding that with the large absolute point moves making headlines, in percentage terms of the entire market, they are smaller than many other comparable declines. And that was with the one thing that stays on people’s mind as a fair proxy for how “the economy” is doing. Overall, we need more simplicity because we must sell external development to a reluctant public that has other things eating away at their attention. In this manner, perhaps a composite index like the HDI or the I-AHDI is a better choice because it boils down things to one metric. The other alternative here would be to have democratically unaccountable technocrats in charge of the external development issues in the already developed countries.


Works Cited

Cypher, J. M. (2014). The process of economic development. London: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group.

Sen, Amartya K. (1988). “The Concept of Development” in H. Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan (eds.), Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 1, Amsterdam: North — Holland, pp. 9–26.

Stiglitz, J. E., Sen, A., & Fitoussi, J. (2010). Mismeasuring our lives: Why GDP doesn’t add up: The report. New York: New Press.

Thursday, December 20, 2018

J. Edgar Mihelic for Brookfield Library Trustee


When the community turned against the referendum in 2016, I thought that Brookfield missed an opportunity to invest in the future by going to the debt markets at a historically good bargain.

The need for a new facility in 2016 was real, and the need continues to be real. I have been involved in the next phase of development. As the Vice President of the Foundation for the Brookfield Library for the last two years, I have helped find private investors to make a new, reimagined facility closer to reality.



The new building is still only on paper though. The next four years will see that concept become reality, and I hope to represent the community as we take the idea on the drawing board and create it in brick in mortar. With an MBA from Concordia and a Master’s in Economics from Roosevelt in progress, I have the education; with eight years of experience at a local nonprofit; I can represent the citizens of Brookfield as a steward of their tax dollars as we all invest in our future. 

It is not just about building the new library. That same experience gives me the knowledge and know-how to help support the whole mission of the library and its programs.   

Tuesday, November 27, 2018

Mitigating Inequality: Policy from Behind the Veil of Ignorance


The financial crisis of 2008 was a major turning point in our country’s history. The stock market had multiple days of losing hundreds of points as the political and economic institutions and the leaders grappled with ways to staunch the bleeding (Amadeo). The inflection point of the crisis coincided with a presidential election. That election was polling close until Barak Obama pulled away and won, placing the Democrats at the head of the executive branch while they still had their majority in both houses of congress that they gained in 2006. During the transition, Congress passed a bailout for the banks known as TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program), and the Federal Reserve flooded banking the system with liquidity, pushing the federal funds rate to its lowest point in history (Amadeo). As Obama came into office, he and his economic advisors realized that the lame-duck motions of the end of the Bush Administration would not be enough to fill the hole left by the financial crisis. Obama and the new congress narrowly passed a stimulus of $787 billion dollars. The bill, ARRA (American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009), was designed such that even though many people saw direct benefits from the new law, it did not create a new constituency. In fact, some polls showed that people thought that their taxes increased (“ARRA”).


The effects of ARRA were welcomed, but even looking back in 2015, the CBO estimated the program had limited effect: “The effects of ARRA on output peaked in the first half of 2010 and have since diminished CBO estimates. The effects of ARRA on employment are estimated to have lagged slightly behind the effects on output; CBO estimates that the employment effects began to wane at the end of 2010.” (“Impact”, p 3). The limited effects were anticipated at the start from some economists. Paul Krugman, Nobel Prize winner and New York Times Columnist, gave a speech in early 2009 noting: “[ARRA]’s helpful, but it does not cover even one-third of the gap, so it’s disappointing. Out of the $789 billion approved, only about $600 billion adds real stimulus. You’ve only got $600 billion to fill a $2.9 trillion hole.” (America). Economists like Krugman wanted the stimulus package to be big enough to fill the hole that was created with the crisis and to kick-start spending. Even with a headline number that made all but the most jaded gasp, the number was not big enough to fill the hole and create the jobs needed to get the economic activity up to par, with what it had been before the recession had started.

The recession, however, was a bit different from other recessions. Between the depth of job losses and the slowness of the recovery, the Brookings Institute estimates that though the absolute number of jobs hit the pre-recession level as of April 2014, it was not until July of 2017 that the overall gap closed adjusting for demographic variables such as population growth and aging. This now decade-long recovery had economist calling the recovery “L-shaped” or a “jobless recovery” since similar returns to normalcy aftershocks in 1981 and 1990 only took 40 and 48 months (“jobs gap”). The same study notes that the recession and recovery were also notable for variabilities in place and race and educational attainment. In addition, where the real-estate bubbles were higher, the crash was greater, and the recovery took longer. For whites, and those with more education, the crash was not as deep nor as long lasting in term of overall employment.

The depth of the crash and the long duration of the recovery matters in part because the political response. Once Obama was sworn in as President, Republicans in congress dragged their feet on teaming with the Democrats. Despite attempting to work with the Republicans, the ARRA stimulus was passed with no GOP votes in the house and only three voting in the Senate. (Calmes). The dissatisfaction with the recovery effort spread out from the halls of congress. In early 2009, Rick Santelli, a commentator on the cable financial news channel CNBC, went on a tirade broadcasting from the floor of the Chicago Mercantile exchange, saying, “The government is promoting bad behavior. How about this, president and new administration, why don’t you put up a website to have people vote on the Internet as a referendum to see if we really want to subsidize the losers’ mortgages.” Then he turned, and the traders clapped, adding, “President Obama, are you listening? We’re thinking of having a Chicago Tea Party in July. All you capitalists show up to Lake Michigan, I’m going to start organizing. I’ll tell you what: If you read our Founding Fathers — people like Benjamin Franklin and Jefferson — what we’re doing in this country now is making them roll over in their graves.” (Kirell). Santelli’s monologue started a movement that had been coalescing against President Obama and the Democrats. The GOP in the next years at the federal level dug in its heels and opposed any initiatives in the House and the Senate that the Democrats proposed, from health care reform to lowering the risks in the banking system to try to stave off another crisis of the magnitude of that in 2008. (Staff). The Tea party resistance to Obama paid off for the Republicans as in 2010 where the Republicans lowered the Democrats’ majority to below the filibuster-proof threshold and gained an absolute majority in the house (“Senate Results Map”). Republicans were heartened with their new powers, with Speaker Boehner outlining his plan: “The single most important thing we want to achieve is for President Obama to be a one-term president.” (Barr).





The backlash to the bailouts and the slow recovery was not just on the right. After the wave election that put many of the Tea Party Republicans in place, there was a movement on the left. Posters from the magazine Adbusters went up in New York and spread on social media. The poster had a ballerina standing atop the famous Wall Street Bull statue. On the bottom was the “hashtag #OccupyWallStreet. From an initial protest, the Occupation grew. It was not just at the original planned site in lower Manhattan. Encampments grew up in cities large and small in the fall of 2011. The main criticism of the encampment was that there were no direct demands. Occupy was a loose confederacy of anarchical gatherings. Winter came and the police broke up the main encampment. The ultimate legacy of the gatherings was that a new light was brought on the gross inequities of wealth and income that existed in our society. Wall Street bankers had to look face to face with protesters in the camps. Online, the phrase “We are the 99%” spread as people told their stories and spread them with their social media networks. (Lalinde). There was not as strong an electoral consequence with the Occupy Movement as there was with the Tea Party. Obama did win reelection against Mitt Romney in 2012 but did not make up for the wave election in the house or greatly make any movement in the Senate. (“Election Results”) Bernie Sanders, Senator from Vermont, used rhetoric that was familiar to the Occupiers in his bid for the Democratic Nomination in 2016. This bid was ultimately unsuccessful as he lost to entrenched party favorite Hillary Clinton. Clinton, in turn, lost to the GOP candidate Donald Trump who won a narrow victory speaking with exclusionary language and nationalistic triumphalism, running an outside campaign like the Tea Parties eight years earlier.

The crisis of 2008 was such a turning point for the United States because a clear line can be drawn from the crash and the response to it both from monetary and fiscal policy standpoints and the rhetoric surrounding that response from both sides of the political aisle. The response echoes down today to our president threatening trade wars with anyone who looks at him funny with the lowering of the tax rates on high earners and their capital gains. What it comes down to on both sides are questions of distribution and equity. How do we define the pie, how do we decide how it is divided, and who gets what parts of the pie? In this paper, we will explore the ideological response to the crisis, as inequality gained greater attention after 2008. We will examine gathering evidence of inequities with the American economic system as these inequities exacerbate and give lie to the idea of America as the land of equality and the land of opportunity. Finally, we will suggest a different ethical framework for evaluating the economic systems, and show how policy choices can be driven by that framework.

There are several different ways to look at what the pie means economically. The first way is to define income that comes in on an hourly basis or in terms of salary. Other things that we might include in this measure are such things as benefits or bonuses or deferred income. This measure of wage income is defined as pay. To take a broader conception of the money coming in, there are many other ways that someone could receive a flow of funds such as dividends, capital gains, royalties, and rent. The sum of all the money coming in over a defined time span is your income. (Galbraith p. 2)
A different way to look at the pie is to see the total of a collection of assets. As James Galbraith explains, this sum “includes financial assets, such as money, and stocks and bonds at their market value. It includes the value of houses, real estate, art, automobiles, jewelry, and other possessions, net of any debts held against them. And it includes the capital value of present or future income flows.” (Galbraith p. 3).

Once the pie is defined, there are several different ways to compare the differences in either income or wealth. One can look at an individual’s share of the pie, or perhaps the household’s share of the pie. The aggregate totals at a high level can be looked at to get a sense of the distribution and to examine how the overall distribution has changed over time. As Galbraith notes, one simple way to make comparisons is to “line all the observations from low to high and to count them off in percentage terms, point by point” (Galbraith p. 61). This ordinal comparison then allows the examiner to look at ratios of certain percentile groups, for example, how much income the group in the middle as earns defined by the 50th percentile as how the group at the 90th percentile earns much income.

One of the most common measurements of inequality is the Gini Coefficient. The Gini Coefficient is based on the Lorentz curve. To map out the coefficient, one takes the cumulative share of income and draws out a curve against the cumulative share of people. If there were perfect equality in the population being studied, the curve would be a straight line with a 45-degree angle. In practice, there are very few examples of perfect equality. What is seen instead is that as you move from left to right, the total share of the income grows slower than the total share of people. In all but perfectly populations, the units on the right will have more than the units on the left. This creates a curve that is below the line of equality, and the Gini Coefficient is measured as the ratio of the area between the line of equality and the Lorentz curve over the total area. The more unequal in distribution the wealth or income of population is, the higher the Gini Coefficient. The highest a Gini Coefficient can theoretically be is a measure of one, where one person accrues all the income or wealth of a measured population (Galbraith p. 64–65). At the other end would be where all members of a population have equal share of the resources.

Having a measurement like percentile ratios or the Gini Coefficient means that you can start to measure inequality within or across countries and across time. In the western countries, especially the United States, the broad consensus is that in the past few decades inequality is increasing. Galbraith notes “The economies of almost all nation states have experienced significant increases in economic inequality in the past generation, so that with almost no exceptions, the world’s people belong to more unequal countries than they did in 1960 or even in 1980” (Galbraith p 123). Branko Milanovic, former chief economist of the IMF, traces the move in US Gini from “a historically low level of about 35 Gini points until the trough in 1979. After that, it rose steadily, reaching over 40 Gini points by the second decade of the twenty-first century (Milanović p. 71). French Economist Thomas Piketty looks at similar data and calls the increase in income inequality an “explosion,” as the US income for the upper decile (top ten percent) increased from between 30 to 35 percent to between 45–50 percent. Piketty postulates that “The shape of the curve is rather impressively steep, and it is natural to wonder how long such a rapid increase can continue: if change continues at the same pace, for example, the upper decile will be raking in 60 percent of national income by 2030” (Piketty p. 294).
Ultimately, this high and increasing inequality of both wealth and income in the United States is detrimental because there are many negative social effects. We have already seen one of these, in the political polarization that has become exacerbated since the financial crisis in 2008. The crisis was like the tide going out. The false good times of the bubble that preceded the crisis masked many negative effects of inequality that existed — and not just the loss of jobs, income, and wealth that the crisis carried with it. In The Price of Inequality, Nobel-Prize winning economist examines in-depth many ways that the high inequalities were exacerbated by the crisis. One of these is that the composition of wealth for earners at different point on the distribution scale. Stiglitz notes that the poor and middle class, if they have any positive net worth at all, have most of their wealth tied up in their housing stock. So that when the housing market turned downward, it is these people with their wealth tied up in housing that suffered most. He notes that on the well-off side of the scale this was less of an issue: “At the top, CEOs were remarkably successful in maintaining their high pay; after a slight dip in 2008, the ratio of CEO annual compensation to that of the typical worker by 2010 was back to what it had been before the crisis, to 243 to 1” (Stiglitz p. 3).

This greater bifurcation between the middle and the top creates unequal societies, and not just in theory. Stiglitz dreads a world full of gated communities for the rich while the poor and middle class exist as servants, a world where “populists promise the masses a better life, only to disappoint”. He continues drawing this word as one where there is an absence of hope for most people, knowing that their state in life is one that they cannot move on from (Stiglitz p. 3). These are lines written in 2012 but speak to us now as uncanny warnings from the past. Stiglitz draws a grim picture of the American economy as he saw it when he was writing in the immediate aftermath of the Tea Party wave and the rise of the Occupy Movement. For him, those at the top were capturing most of the gains and inequality was increasing. In addition, there were many different policy decisions that led to a more precarious existence at the lower end of the distribution. The economy as a whole was growing slower, so what growth the poorer were able to capture was less and less. The safety net was in tatters as unemployment insurance, food stamps, and cash assistance were increasingly hard to get. For those who had lost their jobs in the recession, the federal government stopped extending unemployment even though the job market remained weak. These problems led to problems with health, with Stiglitz highlighting that “America’s poor have a life expectancy that is almost ten percent lower than that of those at the top” (Stiglitz p. 14). Even those that have fought through these limitations, there is less equality of opportunity. A poor child who does well in school is less likely to graduate than a rich child who does not do as well in school; even after graduating, the children of the poor are less well off than the children of the rich (Stiglitz p. 19). For Stiglitz, this can be summed up that “America has more inequality than any other advanced industrial country, and it does less to correct these inequities, and inequality is growing more than in many other countries” (Stiglitz p. 24).
The problems with inequality are not just at the individual or economic level. For Stiglitz there is an invisible thumb on the scale, as inequality is not just driven by market forces. Instead, “much of the inequality that exists today is a result of government policy, both what the government does and what it does not do. Government hast the power to move money from the top to the bottom and the middle, or vice versa” (Stiglitz p. 30). This illustrates the main social problem with inequality as Stiglitz sees it. Inequality does not just happen, or if it does the impact is not made better through policy, instead it is often increased through various kinds of rent-seeking such that: “Those with power use that power to strengthen their economic and political positions” Stiglitz p. 29). Those with power have done such things as using their political influence on shape policy that is pro-business instead of pro market (Stiglitz p. 35), they have created a vast financial system that absorbs more value than it creates, funneling resources to the top (Stiglitz p. 37). They have maneuvered themselves to be granted license to valuable natural resource deposits (Stiglitz p. 39) or created barriers of entry to business, creating monopoly rents that those at the top can take advantage of (Stiglitz p. 44). All these structures allow the already powerful and wealthy to cement their hold on the income and wealth of the country. It also creates a positive feedback loop that is positive only for them, as it allows them to capture more resources which in turn gives the already rich more money and then more power and so on to the third and fourth degree.

Not everyone believes in a critique of inequality like that presented by Stiglitz. In 2013, Harvard Professor Gregory Mankiw made waves with his essay “Defending the One Percent” that was eventually published in the Journal of Economic Perspectives. In the essay, Mankiw directly dismisses Stiglitz’s thesis, saying, “I was not convinced. Stiglitz’s narrative relies more on exhortation and anecdote than on any systemic evidence. There is not good reason to believe that rent-seeking by the rich is more pervasive today than it was in the 1970s” (Mankiw p. 26). Instead, Mankiw makes the case for what is called “skills-based technological change” where the demand for skilled labor goes up and thus the pay rate for those possessing the valued skills goes up in tandem with the demand for their skills. In the essay, Mankiw tries to diminish the arguments of people who think that inequality is a problem. For example, he looks at the finance industry and sees not a nest of rent seeking, but instead an issue “primarily one of efficiency. A well-functioning economy needs the correct allocation of talent. The last thing we need is for the next Steve Jobs to forgo Silicon Valley in order to join the high frequency traders on Wall Street” (Mankiw p. 24). For Mankiw, the one percenters will become one percenters no matter where in the economy they are, so what we need to worry about socially is not that they exist, but that they are doing productive jobs in the economy. He is also not concerned that many of these top earners come from families of top earners. Mankiw looks at a measure of mobility that Stiglitz draws, one where we should measure the odds of ending up in the top ten percent and say that a well-structured society, these odds would be the same for the rich child or the poor child. Mankiw waves that away by saying we should be looking more at the state of the poor and not the lofty heights of the rich (Mankiw p 25).

Mankiw is not the only supporter of the current level of inequality. In a title similarly wearing its allegiances on its sleeve, Edward Conard, a former business partner of Mitt Romney, released a book in response to the rising interest around inequality, called The Upside of Inequality. In it, Conard tries to show why many of the points that more left-wing economists make about inequality are more myth than truth. He argues that incentives do matter, that those at the top have earned their pay, that there is no secular stagnation and investment opportunities are out there, that the middle class is doing well, and that mobility has not declined. The thesis he goes back to repeatedly is that “Higher payoffs for success increase the supply of properly trained talent, and these higher payoffs motivate innovators, entrepreneurs, and investors to take risks. […] Faster growth increases middle- and working-class wages when the supply of lesser-skilled labor is constrained” (Conard p. 5). Now, Conard is not an economist and he is writing to non-economists from his class position, but he does occupy a space in the business and publishing elite by previously having been a best-selling author. Thus, his pronouncements do hold some weight when he claims that the “Critics of the 1 percent are wrong” that they have not achieved their success through cronyism or unearned rents, instead they “have largely earned their success by commercializing successful innovation” (Conard p. 189). As we saw earlier, he is not a lone voice, but echoing the arguments of a noted Harvard professor writing in the AEA’s general interest journal.

To fully determine which of the two sides is right, we need to turn towards the stories we tell ourselves about ourselves to examine the criteria by with we judge which is more correct. Does the economic system as it exists reward those who are already powerful through various rents that are created and enforced by the well off, or is the economy a blind lottery that is rewarding the skilled without hindering the advancement of people through the class structure?

One of the things that is fairly unique about the United States that it shares with other nations of the Americas is that it is new as a country. By the time of independence, there had been only a century and a half of continuous European settlement. This framing is not to dismiss the tens of thousands of years of native settlement of the land of the Americas. They played a role in inspiring some of our political ideals (Loewen p. 82), as well as playing a continual role in these stories as the dwellers on the frontier as mutual contact changed both cultures (Loewen p. 110). The land that we call the United States was not a tabula rasa for the white settlers, but instead an active social plane that was depopulated in acts of plague and famine through settler agency and negligence. That is not the story that we tell about ourselves. The native peoples are often side characters if they come up at all. The story of America that we tell the children so that they are proud to be Americans often starts with settlement in the early 1600s with some people in buckled hats and then jumps forward to developed cities in the 1770s. It is there, in Philadelphia where the name that are familiar to schoolchildren laid pen to paper, declaring their sovereignty as men: “We hold these truths to be self-evident, that all men are created equal, that they are endowed by their Creator with certain unalienable rights, that among these are Life, Liberty and the Pursuit of happiness” and declaring their sovereignty from the British yoke: “ these United Colonies are, and of Right ought to be Free and Independent States” (“Declaration”). This document kicked off a war in which the small rebellious band of patriots showed that freedom from the yoke of tyranny was possible, and to set forth on a road to self-governance was the goal of the enlightened men. In popular imagination, the Articles of Confederation might as well not exist, so the next step after declaring independence and beating the English was to write the constitution. These men got together and debated a new social contract in a way that has not been fully replicated in our nation’s history. The Constitution was the best possible, state of the art. It had three branches, and a stronger legislature than the other two branches. It also had a Senate that was answerable to the states and a House of Representatives that was answerable to the people.

The story of America is not a single strand of triumph, however. The story of America has been one of conflict both physical and ideological. Often you hear the initial conflict between the Hamiltonians and the Jeffersonians, the original urban rural divide, and one that grew even from the document itself, one that enshrined slave-holding while declaring at the start “We the People of the United States, in Order to form a more perfect Union, establish Justice, insure domestic Tranquility, provide for the common defence, promote the general Welfare, and secure the Blessings of Liberty to ourselves and our Posterity” (“Constitution”). It was this document, measured but imperfect that Hamilton, Jay, and Madison defended in the Federalist Papers, asking, “Whether societies of men are really capable or not of establishing good government from reflection and choice, or are forever destined to depend for their political constitutions on accident and force.” (Hamilton et al p. 27). The founders, for all their faults, worked at a groping towards perfectibility — an ideal that is forged in enlightenment thought. This perfectibility was bound up in conflict. In another of the Federalists, Number 10, Madison recognizes the competing claims on wealth and power in a republic:

But the most common and durable source of factions has been the various and unequal distribution of property. Those who hold and those who are without property have ever formed distinct interests in society. Those who are creditors, and those who are debtors, fall under a like discrimination. A landed interest, a manufacturing interest, a mercantile interest, a moneyed interest, with many lesser interests, grow up of necessity in civilized nations, and divide them into different classes, actuated by different sentiments and views. The regulation of these various and interfering interests forms the principal task of modern legislation and involves the spirit of party and faction in the necessary and ordinary operations of the government. (Hamilton et al p. 74 emphasis added).

The foundation laid was built upon brick by brick, as when De Tocqueville visited fifty years later, his opening remarks in his travelogue and ode to Democracy in America was to note: “Amongst the novel objects that attracted my attention during my stay in the United States, nothing struck me more forcibly than the general equality of conditions.” (De Tocqueville p. 11). The question is how we got from the place where the founders were careful to note the balance between competing classes to the one where foreign visitors would call our equality the most notable thing about our civilization to one where some of our most eminent economists are worried about the rich creating a separate society walled off from the rest of their fellow citizens. One answer would be to look at a separate, but related thread that flows from founding ideals. There is the idea of the individual alone in nature, at the frontier who can make or break his or her own destiny because America is the land of opportunity. It runs from the pioneers and the gold rushes to the entrepreneurial spirit of gilded age robber barons from Carnegie to Rockefeller to Ford to Gates to Zuckerberg. This is the America that capitalism made with the risk-taker’s hand on the tiller, a dynamic system where the Schumpeterian creative destruction contains the seeds of the new rebirth (Schumpeter p. 84). These are the two conflicts that have been in tension from the earliest days of society, but these tensions helped birth the American dream, one where everyone had a shot, and one where, as the sociologist Robert Putnam puts in in his examination of one town’s encounter with modernity and the loss of that dream: “The children of manual workers and of professionals came from similar homes and mixed unselfconsciously in schools and neighborhoods, in scout troops and church groups”. This was a world where families were intact with homes owned by those families and a sense of community existed — there were no strangers (Putnam p. 34).

What is interesting is that in many ways, American society is failing both ideals, the land of equality and the land of opportunity. As we saw above, both the Occupy and Tea Party movements birthed books and thought on inequality in the society, and research continues to shine a light on the struggles of average Americans. For example, Princeton economists Anne Case and Angus Deaton made headlines as they surveyed the white working class, telling their readers: “Although midlife mortality continued to fall in other rich countries, and in other racial and ethnic groups in the United States, mortality rates for WNHs age 45–54 increased from 1998 through 2013. Mortality declines from the two biggest killers in middle age — cancer and heart disease — were offset by marked increases in drug overdoses, suicides, and alcohol-related liver mortality in this period.” (Case and Deaton p. 398). If we accept their findings, we must accept the idea that there is something going on that is more than economically driven, a moral rot created by hopelessness of some kind, post-capitalism anomie. The authors called this excess mortality “deaths of despair”. Looking at it from the accelerated end-of-life perhaps is the wrong starting place though. The American system fails to live up to its founding ideals economically from the beginning. First off is that we still have many of our citizens living in absolute poverty. Dylan Matthews in Vox.com writes “In early 2011, 1.5 million American households, including 3 million children, were living on less than $2 in cash per person per day. Half of those households didn’t have access to in-kind benefits like food stamps, either.” These are numbers, he adds, that have gone up since the Clinton-era welfare reforms. (Matthews). Unfortunately, many of the people who suffer at the low end of the income scale are people of color, those whose ancestors do not fit nicely into the stories we tell about ourselves. Though America ended slavery, it took over eighty years in which all Americans were complicit in the exploitation of the slave population, north and south. These inequities continue. A report from the Center for American Progress notes, “In 2016, the median wealth for black and Hispanic families was $17,600 and $20,700, respectively, compared with white families’ median wealth of $171,000.” This gap can be observed “regardless of households’ education, marital status, age, or income.” (Hanks). Education reinforces these inequities, as recent research from Georgetown University’s Center on Education and Workforce notes that in Alabama, “32 of every 100 college-age residents are black, but only seven of every 100 students at the state’s selective public colleges are black.” (Mitchell). Even those who do get to school often find themselves loaded with student loan debt, which Julie Margetta-Morgan, a fellow at the Roosevelt Institute, calls a “failed social experiment where the government thought that it would be fine to give people student debt because that would pay off in the long run and we’re seeing that’s not the case.” (Berman). Increasing educational attainment has not full paid off in terms of life outcomes. One mechanism is that as more people go to college, jobs can require more credentials for the same position at the same pay. This credential inflation devalues the return to the new degrees.

At the same time the idea of opportunity is dropping. One way to look at this is the creation of new businesses. Though the companies in Silicon Valley get the lion’s share of the attention, and the idea that the current American business model is one of the new Schumpeterian creative destruction as the tech elite disrupt existing business models, the light shined over there ignores the rest of the economy. The rest of the economy shows a different story. Census Bureau reporting tracks the creation of new companies. In 1980, almost fifteen percent of all companies were new companies, defined as companies as less than a year old. By 2015, that total had dropped almost half, to eight percent. New companies inject the dynamism in the economy, create new jobs, and are often more productive. One economist who has studied this, Marshall Steinbaum, points to the power of existing firms: “You’ve got rising market power. In general, that makes it hard for new businesses to compete with incumbents. Market power is the story that explains everything.” (Casselman). On the other side of it is a lack of mobility. One way of looking at mobility is how a person’s initial position in the income distribution cements the ultimate position in the income distribution. Examining data on this from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, Bhashkar Mazumder notes a broad consensus that intergenerational income mobility is “relatively low in the United States, especially when compared with other advanced economies”. Mazumder observes that the view of America as a highly mobile society and a “land of opportunity” may be unwarranted. (Mazumder). Part of this is limited by geographic immobility. Raj Chetty and his coauthors of the American Opportunity Atlas where they “trace the roots of outcomes such as poverty and incarceration back to the neighborhoods in which children grew up. We find that children’s outcomes vary sharply across nearby tracts” (Chetty et al p. 2). Geography is destiny as past social engineering projects like redlining and selective zoning, combined with white flight and blockbusting, have created zones of entrenched poverty, so that looking at “data shows many neighborhoods where families had little money decades ago and produced kids who make little money as adults. And even though many of the kids have moved away, these neighborhoods continue to house families that make little money.” (Reyes). Finally, we also see that moving away is difficult. In examining geographic mobility data, the Brookings Institute notes that those lower on the income scale are able to move. This geographic stasis being a problem as moving, throughout the nation’s history, has been a way for seeking out new opportunity and bettering one’s self. Of course, moving takes resources the poor do not often have, “diminished mobility is often caused by limited means: young adults from low-income families may have less of a family safety net to fall back on in the event of employment setbacks, less information about opportunities in distant locations, or simply fewer resources to fund a move.” (Nunn). Ultimately, from the evidence we have looked at here, the conclusion is easy to draw. Those who are concerned about inequality and its effects have a stronger case. Not only is absolute poverty persistent, but also through the educational system race based, class based and geographical inequities follow people through their lives so that it is much harder to move both through the income distribution and in place. Putnam’s mingled communities of his 1950’s American dream have turned towards the Stiglitzian fear of gated communities where the rich never see the poor unless they are checking them out at the store or moving their lawn.

Why does this inequality persist? To understand the debate between those who are concerned about inequality and those who dismiss it we need to look at the ethical framework driving the arguments of those who have the power and make the policy decisions that help entrench the rich and prevent mobility of the poor. This understanding must come from an understanding of economic history. The standard welfare theorems of economics have their base in utilitarianism philosophy from the nineteenth century, when there was less of a solid wall between philosophy and economics. The thinker John Stewart Mill defined utilitarianism, in his book of the same name thusly: “The creed which accepts as the foundation of morals “utility” or the “greatest happiness principal” holds that actions are right in the proportion as they tend to promote happiness; wrong as they tend to produce the reverse of happiness. By happiness is intended pleasure and the absence of pain; by unhappiness, pain and privation of pleasure.” (Mill p. 7). On the face of things, this is not a bad framework for a moral stance, but it does beg some questions from an economic standpoint, about units and aggregates: How does one measure happiness, is happiness subjective, are there diminishing returns to happiness, what does a society where happiness is maximized look like? Economists coming after Mill formalized these questions into the marginal neoclassical economics that we know today, where every economic actor is solely a self-interested agent. These self-interested agents as they maximize their happiness will eventually attain a point of Pareto Optimality, which is an outcome where there would be no other outcome within the existing economic constraints that would make one person better off without making any other person worse off (Bowles et al p. 60). A problem with a Pareto condition is that there are many Pareto Optimal distributions. If the Gini Coefficient is one, and one economic actor has all the resources, this is an “Optimal” point, as it is impossible to make any of the other economic actors in the population better off without taking resources away from the singular economic actor who has somehow obtained all the resources. What the Pareto Optimal condition based on utilitarian thinking does is cement the status quo as it assumes that the current position is optimal in terms of efficiency because the point has been reached through mutually beneficent trade. In this view, if inequality exists, it is through the benign workings of the market mechanism and not through the exercise of power of any sort, be it economic or political.

What is needed is a different perception of ethics than the one based on utilitarianism happiness maximization. By using a different framework, namely that as outlined by the philosopher John Rawls in his A Theory of Justice, policy decisions of both economic and political import will be made in a more equitable manner. Rawls, in his work, uses the utilitarian framework as one that runs counter to his preferences of justice as fairness. He writes, “The striking feature of the utilitarian view of justice is that it does not matter, except indirectly, how the sum of satisfactions is distributed among individuals,” continuing, “Society must allocate its means of satisfaction, whatever these are, rights and duties, opportunities and privileges, and various forms of wealth, so as to achieve the maximum it can” (Rawls p. 26). Instead of using the utilitarian framework, Rawls looks instead at utilizing a social contract. With this social contract, the basics are that the principal of justice are those so that the basic structure of society is based on original agreement. In this agreement, the basic rules of the game would be played out, where “Men are to decide in advance how they are to regulate their claims against one another and what is to be the foundation of the charter of their society” (Rawls p. 11). As we have seen earlier, the United States has just this chance earlier in its history as they wrote the constitution and its framers defended the document in the Federalist papers. The key part of a Rawlsian social contract is that the for the framers of the contract “no one knows his place in society, his class position or social status, nor does anyone know his fortune in the distribution of natural assets and abilities, his intelligence, his strength, and the like” (Rawls p. 12). The formulation is such that no one when choosing the setup of society knows where they will be in terms of class or race or in the income distribution so that they cannot make policy to benefit themselves or their peers. The blind position is called by Rawls the “Veil of Ignorance”. The Rawlsian approach is not a novel approach for evaluating inequality. Anthony Atkinson, in his book Inequality: What Can Be Done, acknowledges that a Rawlsian framework “takes us well beyond utilitarianism” (Atkinson p. 12). Mankiw also regards the position in his ode to the one percent. He takes the argument and tries to over-extend it: “Take the logic a bit further. In this original position, people would be concerned about more than being born rich or poor. They would also be concerned about health outcomes. Consider kidneys, for example.” Mankiw want the reader to imagine a world where all outcomes are considered and thus from the start, we would sign insurance contracts against having kidney disease. (Mankiw p. 32). What Mankiw fails to consider is that uncertainty about the original position is the entire point of justice as fairness, so that the framers of the social contract make sure that all have access to the needed resources.

What Mankiw does as he tries to reduce the veil of ignorance to absurdity is raises the question of what policy-making looks like in a world in which we have accepted a different theory of social justice that is not based on utilitarian thinking. To think about these policy recommendations, it is simple enough to walk back though the identified current inequities and suggest alternatives. Americans like to think of themselves as working in the land of opportunity and the land of the free but so much of the rhetoric is about the current position and not what would be the most equitable from an original position. Policy is seen in terms of zero-sum games so that any redistribution is seen as stealing what has been rightfully earned. Barring another major civil war or constitutional convention, there will not be any chance to formalize the social contract in line with a Rawlsian approach to justice. This means that we need to think of policy as if we are behind the veil of ignorance, which is a harder thing to do, since we are already aware of our class and race geographic positions and cannot readily deny them. One example of policy that would be recommended is to rethink how we fund or institutions of education from the primary to the tertiary level. The current method of funding at the primary and secondary level are based on property taxes. By funding them in this manner, the more well off districts can create the atmosphere for better learning and more opportunity for their students. At the same time, those students in poorer districts eat lunches of low quality that are prepared at a central office and study at schools that do not have their own library. As we saw, this inequity passes onto the college level, were the makeup of the college classes are tilted towards the well off and towards the racial majorities at the expense of the minorities. Those from the less well-off areas who borrow end up with debt which replicates the cycle of poverty as increasing student debt inhibits household formation and other consumption that meets the expected standards of living. So instead of looking at the funding of schools from local tax receipts, this could be funded at the state or national level to erase some of the inequities of geography and to give all the same opportunities at an educational level. A counter example to this methodology is looking at the implementation of the Affordable Care Act. By relying on states to design rules for and implement the program, there is a divergent access to health care across the fifty states. Reformulating the educational taxation methodology is not a rewriting of the social contract, but one place we could start as we grasp towards creating a society that we would want to be part of even if we did not know where we would start from.

And yet! School funding just scratches the surface of what is possible if we were to move towards a non-utilitarian ethical framework. A society could be created that moves back towards American ideals and against the gated communities where many would never have the chance to scale the walls because they are so high and the gates are so thick. Nevertheless, this is not to dismiss the possibility. With the Occupy Movement and Sanders candidacy and the long shadow of the 2008 financial crisis, a new generation has arisen acknowledged that the current social structure is untenable.


Bibliography
All Too Humanitarian. (n.d.). Retrieved October 21, 2018, from https://www.commonwealmagazine.org/all-too-humanitarian
Amadeo, K. (n.d.). When and Why Did the Stock Market Crash in 2008? Retrieved from https://www.thebalance.com/stock-market-crash-of-2008-3305535
America, F. 1. (n.d.). Nobel Laureate Paul Krugman: Too Little Stimulus in Stimulus Plan. Retrieved from http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article/nobel-laureate-paul-krugman-too-little-stimulus-in-stimulus-plan/
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA): Details. (n.d.). Retrieved from https://www.thebalance.com/arra-details-3306299
Atkinson, A. B. (2018). Inequality — what can be done? Harvard University Press.
Barr, A., Cook, S. A., Carlin, J. P., Moss, B. P., & Cooper, R. (2010, October 28). The GOP’s no-compromise pledge. Retrieved from https://www.politico.com/story/2010/10/the-gops-no-compromise-pledge-044311
Berman, J. (2018, October 18). America’s $1.5 trillion student-loan industry is a ‘failed social experiment’. Retrieved from https://www.marketwatch.com/story/americas-15-trillion-student-debt-is-a-failed-social-experiment-2018-10-16
Bloomberg View. (2018, May 24). The Rich Get the Most Out of College — Bloomberg View — Medium. Retrieved October 21, 2018, from https://medium.com/bloomberg-view/the-rich-get-the-most-out-of-college-d2ee6ecd8561
C., R., F., N, J., H., N., . . . R, S. (2018, October 11). The Opportunity Atlas: Mapping the Childhood Roots of Social Mobility. Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/papers/w25147
Calmes, J. (2009, January 28). House Passes Stimulus Plan With No G.O.P. Votes. Retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/2009/01/29/us/politics/29obama.html
Case, A., & Deaton, A. (2017). Mortality and Morbidity in the 21st Century. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2017(1), 397–476. doi:10.1353/eca.2017.0005
Casselman, B. (2017, September 20). A Start-Up Slump Is a Drag on the Economy. Big Business May Be to Blame. Retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/2017/09/20/business/economy/startup-business.html
CBO FEBRUARY 2015 Estimated Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act on Employment and Economic Output in 2014. (n.d.). Retrieved from https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/114th-congress-2015-2016/reports/49958-ARRA.pdf
Conard, E. (2016). The upside of inequality: How good intentions undermine the middle class. New York, NY: Portfolio/Penguin.
Delsol, J., Lecaussin, N., & Martin, E. (2017). Anti-Piketty: Capital for the 21st century. Washington, D.C.: Cato Institute.
Galbraith, J. K. (2016). Inequality: What everyone needs to know. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hamilton, A., Madison, J., Rossiter, C., Jay, J., & Kesler, C. R. (2005). The federalist papers. New York: Signet Classics, an imprint of New American Library, a division of Penguin Group (USA).
Hanks, A., Solomon, D., & Weller, C. E. (n.d.). Systematic Inequality. Retrieved from https://www.americanprogress.org/issues/race/reports/2018/02/21/447051/systematic-inequality/
Kirell, A. (2015, October 30). When CNBC Created the Tea Party. Retrieved from https://www.thedailybeast.com/when-cnbc-created-the-tea-party
Lalinde, J., Sacks, R., Guiducci, M., Nicholas, E., & Chafkin, M. (2015, September 17). An Oral History of Occupy Wall Street. Retrieved from https://www.vanityfair.com/news/2012/02/occupy-wall-street-201202
Loewen, J. W. (2018). Lies my teacher told me: Everything your American history textbook got wrong. New York: The New Press.
Mankiw, N. G. (2013). Defending the One Percent. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(3), 21–34. doi:10.1257/jep.27.3.21
Matthews, D. (2015, September 02). Selling plasma to survive: How over a million American families live on $2 per day. Retrieved from https://www.vox.com/2015/9/2/9248801/extreme-poverty-2-dollars
Mazumder, B. (2018). Intergenerational Mobility in the United States: What We Have Learned from the PSID. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 680(1), 213–234. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716218794129
Milanović, B. (2018). Global inequality: A new approach for the age of globalization. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Mill, J. S., & Sher, G. (2002). Utilitarianism. Hackett Publishing Co.
Mitchell, M. (2018, November 16). New report says America’s public universities are separate and unequal. Retrieved from https://chicago.suntimes.com/columnists/college-university-higher-education-separate-unequal-blacks-whites-latinos/
Nunn, R., Parsons, J., & Shambaugh, J. (2018, November 20). Americans aren’t moving to economic opportunity. Retrieved from https://www.brookings.edu/blog/up-front/2018/11/19/americans-arent-moving-to-economic-opportunity/
Piketty, T., & Goldhammer, A. (2017). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge: Belknap Harvard.
Putnam, R. D. (2016). Our kids: The American Dream in crisis. New York: Simon & Schuster.
Rawls, J. (2003). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Reyes, C., & Mahr, J. (2018, October 16). Same city, different opportunities: Study maps life outcomes for children from Chicago neighborhoods. Retrieved from https://www.chicagotribune.com/news/watchdog/ct-american-dream-for-chicago-analysis-htmlstory.html
Schumpeter, J. A. (2009). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper perennial.
Senate Results Map. (n.d.). Retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/elections/2010/results/senate.html
Staff, I. (2018, May 23). Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. Retrieved from https://www.investopedia.com/terms/d/dodd-frank-financial-regulatory-reform-bill.asp
Stiglitz, J. E. (2013). The price of inequality: How todays divided society endangers our future. New York: W.W. Norton.
The closing of the jobs gap: A decade of recession and recovery. (2017, November 07). Retrieved from https://www.brookings.edu/research/the-closing-of-the-jobs-gap-a-decade-of-recession-and-recovery/
The Constitution of the United States: A Transcription. (n.d.). Retrieved from https://www.archives.gov/founding-docs/constitution-transcript
The Declaration of Independence. (n.d.). Retrieved from https://www.archives.gov/founding-docs/declaration
Tocqueville, A. D., Bevan, G., & Tocqueville, A. D. (2003). Democracy in America ; and, Two weeks in the wilderness. London: Penguin.