In
“Technology, Finance and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political
Economy in Retrospect,” Matias Vernengo takes another look at dependency
theory especially as it pertains to the development of Latin America
since the development of the theory. In particular, he looks at how to
reconcile the fact that several periphery countries have in fact been
able to industrialize despite dependency theory. For Vernengo, the
dependency has transferred from the trading of goods to a more financial
peonage, one where debt is the controller of the nation’s destinies at
the periphery.
I
think having a look at Dependency theory is important because for me so
much of economics is both relational and a process. I think it is too
easy to look at a developing country and say to yourself, “Oh that is so
sad, we must do something!” This idea springs forth from the idea that
nations exist in a vacuum and not as part of some world-system. Vernengo
looks at both the Marxist and the Structural traditions of dependency
theory and sees that their commonality lies in the agreement that “the
core of the dependency relation between the center and the periphery
lies in the inability of the periphery to develop an autonomous and
dynamic process of technological innovation” (552). Vernengo argues that
the focus on the technological is wrong as it is finalization that has
trapped the developing nations in their peripheral role. In my view of
the argument, I am more sympathetic to Vernengo’s argument. In the
course of my lifetime I have seen dollar flows come in and crash Mexico
and Russia and South East Asia and Argentina etc. This is not to
discount Baran or Prebish or the schools they worked in. Capital has
many tentacles.
What
thinking about dependency theory has done for me is to make me think of
the totality of the system so that we are not looking at individual
nations in isolation. What this does is make me somewhat pessimistic
about the possibility of growth. I was thinking specifically of some
mathematical truisms. For example, if a country has an initial GDP per
capita of 50 units, and they can grow their output in one year by four
percent, at the end of the year, they will now have an output of 52
units. If this can be sustained year over year, we would laud this
nation for growth over and above what rich nations would do, even if we
would point out that a higher level of growth would be expected from
developing nations because they are not at the technological frontier.
The problem with looking at one nation in isolation is that if you look
at a comparative nation that is twice the size of the first nation. The
second nation has an initial GDP per capita at PPP of 100. This second
nation only must grow at a two percent rate to equal the absolute gain
of the first nation. If the growth rate of the country twice the size
maintains the growth that is half of the smaller country, the gap
between the countries will never close. At some point there will have
been enough growth that the fifty-unit gap will be trivial, but we all
know what the master said about the long run.
I
was interested in taking this thought away from the thought experiment
and into the real world. What I did was to go to the World Bank Website,
and I pulled their data for GDPs per capita for purchasing power
parity. Aware of the limitations of GDP per capita in not catching the
distribution of output internally, it was still a good first pass for
what I was interested in seeing, as its standardized output per person. I
then took the GDPs and expressed them as a ratio of the least developed
country in 2017, here the Central African Republic. The CAR GDP per
capita in 2017 was just under 726 dollars at purchasing power parity.
What is enough to make a person pessimistic is to see just how high the
ratios go. My pessimism driven though experiment was too optimistic.
There are 45 statistical divisions with a ratio higher than 50. The
implication here is that mathematically is that if any of these nations
with a higher GDDP per capita than the Czech Republic grows two percent,
then the Central African Republic needs to literally double its economy
over a year to keep up.
This
is mathematical truism makes me wonder about the possibility of
convergence, as even China, which has been lauded as a growth miracle
over the past thirty years, only has a ratio of 23, meaning that in
comparison to the richest countries, per person it is only a quarter of
the size. So much of its growth in absolute terms has been the sheer
number of people China has. So if we look at that as our best case, if
we really want to talk about the possibilities for convergence, we would
need to be thinking about much slower growth or even-degrowth in the
core countries, and I have a feeling that politically that is a very
heavy lift because the core countries do not want people looking at
development in terms of a world system, but would prefer that people
look at the poor countries and ignore that there is a structural cause
and that there is an ahistorical reason that the people of Niger are in
need.
Works Cited
Vernengo, Matias. “Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect”. Review of Radical Political Economics, Volume 38, №4, Fall 2006, 551–568
Work Bank. GDP per capita, PPP (current international $). (n.d.). Retrieved from https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/ny.gdp.pcap.pp.cd
GDP Per Capita Ratio 2017 | |
Country Name | Ratio |
Central African Republic | 1.00 |
Burundi | 1.01 |
Congo, Dem. Rep. | 1.22 |
Niger | 1.40 |
Malawi | 1.66 |
Mozambique | 1.72 |
Liberia | 1.77 |
Sierra Leone | 2.10 |
Madagascar | 2.14 |
Togo | 2.29 |
Gambia, The | 2.34 |
Guinea-Bissau | 2.34 |
Haiti | 2.50 |
Burkina Faso | 2.57 |
Uganda | 2.57 |
Ethiopia | 2.62 |
Chad | 2.67 |
Afghanistan | 2.72 |
Rwanda | 2.81 |
Low income | 2.97 |
Kiribati | 3.00 |
Mali | 3.05 |
Guinea | 3.09 |
Benin | 3.13 |
Heavily indebted poor countries (HIPC) | 3.30 |
Solomon Islands | 3.34 |
Zimbabwe | 3.35 |
Yemen, Rep. | 3.58 |
Nepal | 3.71 |
Comoros | 3.78 |
Least developed countries: UN classification | 3.84 |
Lesotho | 4.03 |
Tanzania | 4.06 |
IDA only | 4.15 |
Tajikistan | 4.40 |
Vanuatu | 4.42 |
Kenya | 4.53 |
Sao Tome and Principe | 4.62 |
Senegal | 4.75 |
Micronesia, Fed. Sts. | 5.09 |
Cameroon | 5.12 |
Kyrgyz Republic | 5.13 |
IDA total | 5.24 |
Sub-Saharan Africa (excluding high income) | 5.27 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | 5.28 |
Sub-Saharan Africa (IDA & IBRD countries) | 5.28 |
Pre-demographic dividend | 5.29 |
Bangladesh | 5.33 |
Tuvalu | 5.41 |
Cote d'Ivoire | 5.42 |
Mauritania | 5.44 |
Cambodia | 5.52 |
Zambia | 5.54 |
Papua New Guinea | 5.78 |
Marshall Islands | 5.84 |
Fragile and conflict affected situations | 6.13 |
Ghana | 6.19 |
West Bank and Gaza | 6.73 |
Sudan | 6.75 |
Honduras | 6.87 |
IDA blend | 7.41 |
Congo, Rep. | 7.50 |
Pakistan | 7.61 |
Moldova | 7.85 |
Nicaragua | 8.05 |
Nigeria | 8.09 |
Pacific island small states | 8.19 |
Tonga | 8.21 |
Myanmar | 8.49 |
South Asia | 8.95 |
South Asia (IDA & IBRD) | 8.95 |
Samoa | 9.13 |
Angola | 9.15 |
Vietnam | 9.33 |
Uzbekistan | 9.46 |
Cabo Verde | 9.50 |
Lao PDR | 9.67 |
India | 9.72 |
Lower middle income | 9.91 |
Timor-Leste | 9.94 |
Bolivia | 10.41 |
El Salvador | 11.03 |
Guatemala | 11.23 |
Guyana | 11.24 |
Morocco | 11.32 |
Philippines | 11.49 |
Belize | 11.72 |
Eswatini | 11.90 |
Ukraine | 11.94 |
Jamaica | 12.46 |
Jordan | 12.61 |
Bhutan | 12.91 |
Fiji | 13.16 |
Armenia | 13.29 |
Early-demographic dividend | 13.34 |
Dominica | 13.80 |
Namibia | 14.39 |
Georgia | 14.72 |
Kosovo | 14.79 |
Low & middle income | 15.08 |
IDA & IBRD total | 15.45 |
Egypt, Arab Rep. | 15.96 |
Ecuador | 15.96 |
St. Vincent and the Grenadines | 16.18 |
Tunisia | 16.41 |
Middle income | 16.69 |
Indonesia | 16.92 |
Sri Lanka | 17.68 |
Mongolia | 17.80 |
Albania | 17.83 |
Paraguay | 18.02 |
Bosnia and Herzegovina | 18.06 |
Peru | 18.51 |
South Africa | 18.59 |
Middle East & North Africa (excluding high income) | 18.71 |
Middle East & North Africa (IDA & IBRD countries) | 18.86 |
IBRD only | 18.94 |
St. Lucia | 19.23 |
Nauru | 19.50 |
Colombia | 19.94 |
Lebanon | 19.95 |
Latin America & Caribbean (excluding high income) | 20.39 |
Palau | 20.42 |
East Asia & Pacific (excluding high income) | 20.53 |
East Asia & Pacific (IDA & IBRD countries) | 20.75 |
Grenada | 20.83 |
Suriname | 20.88 |
Algeria | 21.02 |
Macedonia, FYR | 21.06 |
Serbia | 21.25 |
Brazil | 21.33 |
Latin America & the Caribbean (IDA & IBRD countries) | 21.65 |
Caribbean small states | 21.73 |
Latin America & Caribbean | 21.77 |
Dominican Republic | 22.08 |
Maldives | 22.94 |
China | 23.15 |
Iraq | 23.28 |
World | 23.35 |
Arab World | 23.36 |
Botswana | 23.40 |
Costa Rica | 23.52 |
Azerbaijan | 23.97 |
Upper middle income | 24.50 |
Late-demographic dividend | 24.51 |
Thailand | 24.62 |
Turkmenistan | 24.79 |
Gabon | 24.90 |
East Asia & Pacific | 24.99 |
Mexico | 25.17 |
Barbados | 25.51 |
Belarus | 25.95 |
Montenegro | 26.66 |
Libya | 27.04 |
Middle East & North Africa | 27.42 |
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) | 28.33 |
Argentina | 28.63 |
Iran, Islamic Rep. | 28.71 |
Bulgaria | 28.86 |
Europe & Central Asia (IDA & IBRD countries) | 29.38 |
Mauritius | 30.73 |
Uruguay | 31.08 |
Small states | 31.42 |
Antigua and Barbuda | 32.33 |
Equatorial Guinea | 33.59 |
Panama | 33.71 |
Chile | 33.94 |
Russian Federation | 35.17 |
Other small states | 35.56 |
Croatia | 36.21 |
Kazakhstan | 36.41 |
Turkey | 36.53 |
Romania | 36.72 |
Greece | 38.02 |
Hungary | 38.72 |
Latvia | 38.84 |
St. Kitts and Nevis | 39.36 |
Central Europe and the Baltics | 39.94 |
Poland | 40.12 |
Seychelles | 40.31 |
Malaysia | 40.57 |
Bahamas, The | 41.92 |
Trinidad and Tobago | 43.50 |
Slovak Republic | 43.55 |
Portugal | 43.63 |
Estonia | 43.73 |
Europe & Central Asia | 44.99 |
Lithuania | 45.45 |
Cyprus | 47.53 |
Slovenia | 48.03 |
Czech Republic | 50.04 |
Spain | 52.34 |
Israel | 52.71 |
Korea, Rep. | 52.81 |
Puerto Rico | 53.54 |
Aruba | 54.29 |
Italy | 54.31 |
Malta | 56.53 |
New Zealand | 56.63 |
European Union | 56.74 |
Oman | 57.41 |
France | 59.03 |
United Kingdom | 59.60 |
Japan | 59.62 |
OECD members | 59.73 |
Euro area | 60.13 |
Finland | 61.80 |
Post-demographic dividend | 63.91 |
Canada | 64.34 |
High income | 65.17 |
Bahrain | 65.47 |
Belgium | 65.90 |
Australia | 66.75 |
Sweden | 69.16 |
Germany | 69.76 |
Denmark | 70.75 |
Austria | 72.18 |
Netherlands | 72.32 |
Iceland | 73.22 |
Saudi Arabia | 74.08 |
Cayman Islands | 80.14 |
North America | 80.22 |
United States | 82.01 |
Norway | 84.60 |
Hong Kong SAR, China | 84.77 |
San Marino | 87.35 |
Switzerland | 89.14 |
Kuwait | 99.10 |
United Arab Emirates | 101.77 |
Ireland | 104.21 |
Brunei Darussalam | 108.60 |
Singapore | 129.36 |
Luxembourg | 142.91 |
Macao SAR, China | 158.58 |
Qatar | 176.84 |