Sunday, February 24, 2019

The Impossibility of Convergence in a Capitalist World System

In “Technology, Finance and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect,” Matias Vernengo takes another look at dependency theory especially as it pertains to the development of Latin America since the development of the theory. In particular, he looks at how to reconcile the fact that several periphery countries have in fact been able to industrialize despite dependency theory. For Vernengo, the dependency has transferred from the trading of goods to a more financial peonage, one where debt is the controller of the nation’s destinies at the periphery.

I think having a look at Dependency theory is important because for me so much of economics is both relational and a process. I think it is too easy to look at a developing country and say to yourself, “Oh that is so sad, we must do something!” This idea springs forth from the idea that nations exist in a vacuum and not as part of some world-system. Vernengo looks at both the Marxist and the Structural traditions of dependency theory and sees that their commonality lies in the agreement that “the core of the dependency relation between the center and the periphery lies in the inability of the periphery to develop an autonomous and dynamic process of technological innovation” (552). Vernengo argues that the focus on the technological is wrong as it is finalization that has trapped the developing nations in their peripheral role. In my view of the argument, I am more sympathetic to Vernengo’s argument. In the course of my lifetime I have seen dollar flows come in and crash Mexico and Russia and South East Asia and Argentina etc. This is not to discount Baran or Prebish or the schools they worked in. Capital has many tentacles.
What thinking about dependency theory has done for me is to make me think of the totality of the system so that we are not looking at individual nations in isolation. What this does is make me somewhat pessimistic about the possibility of growth. I was thinking specifically of some mathematical truisms. For example, if a country has an initial GDP per capita of 50 units, and they can grow their output in one year by four percent, at the end of the year, they will now have an output of 52 units. If this can be sustained year over year, we would laud this nation for growth over and above what rich nations would do, even if we would point out that a higher level of growth would be expected from developing nations because they are not at the technological frontier. The problem with looking at one nation in isolation is that if you look at a comparative nation that is twice the size of the first nation. The second nation has an initial GDP per capita at PPP of 100. This second nation only must grow at a two percent rate to equal the absolute gain of the first nation. If the growth rate of the country twice the size maintains the growth that is half of the smaller country, the gap between the countries will never close. At some point there will have been enough growth that the fifty-unit gap will be trivial, but we all know what the master said about the long run.

I was interested in taking this thought away from the thought experiment and into the real world. What I did was to go to the World Bank Website, and I pulled their data for GDPs per capita for purchasing power parity. Aware of the limitations of GDP per capita in not catching the distribution of output internally, it was still a good first pass for what I was interested in seeing, as its standardized output per person. I then took the GDPs and expressed them as a ratio of the least developed country in 2017, here the Central African Republic. The CAR GDP per capita in 2017 was just under 726 dollars at purchasing power parity. What is enough to make a person pessimistic is to see just how high the ratios go. My pessimism driven though experiment was too optimistic. There are 45 statistical divisions with a ratio higher than 50. The implication here is that mathematically is that if any of these nations with a higher GDDP per capita than the Czech Republic grows two percent, then the Central African Republic needs to literally double its economy over a year to keep up.

This is mathematical truism makes me wonder about the possibility of convergence, as even China, which has been lauded as a growth miracle over the past thirty years, only has a ratio of 23, meaning that in comparison to the richest countries, per person it is only a quarter of the size. So much of its growth in absolute terms has been the sheer number of people China has. So if we look at that as our best case, if we really want to talk about the possibilities for convergence, we would need to be thinking about much slower growth or even-degrowth in the core countries, and I have a feeling that politically that is a very heavy lift because the core countries do not want people looking at development in terms of a world system, but would prefer that people look at the poor countries and ignore that there is a structural cause and that there is an ahistorical reason that the people of Niger are in need.

Works Cited

Vernengo, Matias. “Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect”. Review of Radical Political Economics, Volume 38, №4, Fall 2006, 551–568
Work Bank. GDP per capita, PPP (current international $). (n.d.). Retrieved from https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/ny.gdp.pcap.pp.cd

 
GDP Per Capita Ratio 2017
Country Name Ratio
Central African Republic 1.00
Burundi 1.01
Congo, Dem. Rep. 1.22
Niger 1.40
Malawi 1.66
Mozambique 1.72
Liberia 1.77
Sierra Leone 2.10
Madagascar 2.14
Togo 2.29
Gambia, The 2.34
Guinea-Bissau 2.34
Haiti 2.50
Burkina Faso 2.57
Uganda 2.57
Ethiopia 2.62
Chad 2.67
Afghanistan 2.72
Rwanda 2.81
Low income 2.97
Kiribati 3.00
Mali 3.05
Guinea 3.09
Benin 3.13
Heavily indebted poor countries (HIPC) 3.30
Solomon Islands 3.34
Zimbabwe 3.35
Yemen, Rep. 3.58
Nepal 3.71
Comoros 3.78
Least developed countries: UN classification 3.84
Lesotho 4.03
Tanzania 4.06
IDA only 4.15
Tajikistan 4.40
Vanuatu 4.42
Kenya 4.53
Sao Tome and Principe 4.62
Senegal 4.75
Micronesia, Fed. Sts. 5.09
Cameroon 5.12
Kyrgyz Republic 5.13
IDA total 5.24
Sub-Saharan Africa (excluding high income) 5.27
Sub-Saharan Africa 5.28
Sub-Saharan Africa (IDA & IBRD countries) 5.28
Pre-demographic dividend 5.29
Bangladesh 5.33
Tuvalu 5.41
Cote d'Ivoire 5.42
Mauritania 5.44
Cambodia 5.52
Zambia 5.54
Papua New Guinea 5.78
Marshall Islands 5.84
Fragile and conflict affected situations 6.13
Ghana 6.19
West Bank and Gaza 6.73
Sudan 6.75
Honduras 6.87
IDA blend 7.41
Congo, Rep. 7.50
Pakistan 7.61
Moldova 7.85
Nicaragua 8.05
Nigeria 8.09
Pacific island small states 8.19
Tonga 8.21
Myanmar 8.49
South Asia 8.95
South Asia (IDA & IBRD) 8.95
Samoa 9.13
Angola 9.15
Vietnam 9.33
Uzbekistan 9.46
Cabo Verde 9.50
Lao PDR 9.67
India 9.72
Lower middle income 9.91
Timor-Leste 9.94
Bolivia 10.41
El Salvador 11.03
Guatemala 11.23
Guyana 11.24
Morocco 11.32
Philippines 11.49
Belize 11.72
Eswatini 11.90
Ukraine 11.94
Jamaica 12.46
Jordan 12.61
Bhutan 12.91
Fiji 13.16
Armenia 13.29
Early-demographic dividend 13.34
Dominica 13.80
Namibia 14.39
Georgia 14.72
Kosovo 14.79
Low & middle income 15.08
IDA & IBRD total 15.45
Egypt, Arab Rep. 15.96
Ecuador 15.96
St. Vincent and the Grenadines 16.18
Tunisia 16.41
Middle income 16.69
Indonesia 16.92
Sri Lanka 17.68
Mongolia 17.80
Albania 17.83
Paraguay 18.02
Bosnia and Herzegovina 18.06
Peru 18.51
South Africa 18.59
Middle East & North Africa (excluding high income) 18.71
Middle East & North Africa (IDA & IBRD countries) 18.86
IBRD only 18.94
St. Lucia 19.23
Nauru 19.50
Colombia 19.94
Lebanon 19.95
Latin America & Caribbean (excluding high income) 20.39
Palau 20.42
East Asia & Pacific (excluding high income) 20.53
East Asia & Pacific (IDA & IBRD countries) 20.75
Grenada 20.83
Suriname 20.88
Algeria 21.02
Macedonia, FYR 21.06
Serbia 21.25
Brazil 21.33
Latin America & the Caribbean (IDA & IBRD countries) 21.65
Caribbean small states 21.73
Latin America & Caribbean 21.77
Dominican Republic 22.08
Maldives 22.94
China 23.15
Iraq 23.28
World 23.35
Arab World 23.36
Botswana 23.40
Costa Rica 23.52
Azerbaijan 23.97
Upper middle income 24.50
Late-demographic dividend 24.51
Thailand 24.62
Turkmenistan 24.79
Gabon 24.90
East Asia & Pacific 24.99
Mexico 25.17
Barbados 25.51
Belarus 25.95
Montenegro 26.66
Libya 27.04
Middle East & North Africa 27.42
Europe & Central Asia (excluding high income) 28.33
Argentina 28.63
Iran, Islamic Rep. 28.71
Bulgaria 28.86
Europe & Central Asia (IDA & IBRD countries) 29.38
Mauritius 30.73
Uruguay 31.08
Small states 31.42
Antigua and Barbuda 32.33
Equatorial Guinea 33.59
Panama 33.71
Chile 33.94
Russian Federation 35.17
Other small states 35.56
Croatia 36.21
Kazakhstan 36.41
Turkey 36.53
Romania 36.72
Greece 38.02
Hungary 38.72
Latvia 38.84
St. Kitts and Nevis 39.36
Central Europe and the Baltics 39.94
Poland 40.12
Seychelles 40.31
Malaysia 40.57
Bahamas, The 41.92
Trinidad and Tobago 43.50
Slovak Republic 43.55
Portugal 43.63
Estonia 43.73
Europe & Central Asia 44.99
Lithuania 45.45
Cyprus 47.53
Slovenia 48.03
Czech Republic 50.04
Spain 52.34
Israel 52.71
Korea, Rep. 52.81
Puerto Rico 53.54
Aruba 54.29
Italy 54.31
Malta 56.53
New Zealand 56.63
European Union 56.74
Oman 57.41
France 59.03
United Kingdom 59.60
Japan 59.62
OECD members 59.73
Euro area 60.13
Finland 61.80
Post-demographic dividend 63.91
Canada 64.34
High income 65.17
Bahrain 65.47
Belgium 65.90
Australia 66.75
Sweden 69.16
Germany 69.76
Denmark 70.75
Austria 72.18
Netherlands 72.32
Iceland 73.22
Saudi Arabia 74.08
Cayman Islands 80.14
North America 80.22
United States 82.01
Norway 84.60
Hong Kong SAR, China 84.77
San Marino 87.35
Switzerland 89.14
Kuwait 99.10
United Arab Emirates 101.77
Ireland 104.21
Brunei Darussalam 108.60
Singapore 129.36
Luxembourg 142.91
Macao SAR, China 158.58
Qatar 176.84

No comments:

Post a Comment