To be unemployed has a strict technical
meaning of people who do not have a job but are actively looking for a job. In
the United States, the BLS tracks the number of people who are in the labor
force but do not have a job, in a report issued every month (Krugman &
Wells, 2013, p. 215).
There are multiple ways
to get to that point. Even in a growing economy, people are leaving jobs all
the time. There is a transition period between the time a worker leaves a job
and the time they enter a new job. For example, if a worker wants job in
another state, and they quit one position but the new position is not
immediately forthcoming, the time the worker is in transition from the old job
to the new job is a time they are technically unemployed. This is called
frictional unemployment (Krugman & Wells, 2013, p. 221). Frictional
unemployment is always present in the economy and not necessary and bad thing.
It can mean that people are finding positions that are better fits for their
skill sets.
There is more
pernicious way for a worker to be unemployed. The economy works through cycles,
where there are periods of growth and periods of contraction. The number of
jobs available at times of growth increase and the number of jobs available as
the economy shrinks decreases. Workers caught up in this “cyclical
unemployment” are why the unemployment rate increase is recessions. They are
jobless through the workings of firm-level responses to the business cycle. Fortunately,
for the effected workers, a safety net exists to soften the blow of the job
loss for those affected. For example, federal unemployment insurance was
increased to 99 weeks of benefits in some states during the peak of joblessness
during the most recent recession. They were able to re-enter the workforce when
as the economy once again found itself on a growth track.
The worst form of unemployment
is when there is a surplus of workers even during the peaks in the business
cycle. This surplus is called “structural unemployment,” and can have multiple
causes. The main factor is that the wage rate for whatever reason is above the
equilibrium rate so that the quantity demanded of jobs is less than the
quantity supplied of jobs, and there is a gap where people who would be willing
workers are locked out of work. Examples of this include a minimum wage, where
businesses would hire more workers at a lower rate but the statutory minimum
means those potential workers find themselves without. Another example is labor
unions, where in the same mechanism the negotiated rate is higher than the
clearing rate, and the price floor protects the incumbents who hold the jobs at
the expense of the surplus workers who would work the positions in the simple
supply and demand framework (Krugman & Wells, 2013, p. 168).
References
Krugman,
P. & Wells, R. (2013). Macroeconomics. New York, NY : Worth Publishers
No comments:
Post a Comment