Sunday, February 10, 2019

Everything That Rises Must Converge: Michelle Baddeley and Testing our Models


In “Convergence or Divergence? The Impacts of Globalisation on Growth and Inequality in Less Developed Countries,” Michelle Baddeley explores the impacts of globalization on growth and development. Some of the key parts of theoretical section include effects of trade and capital flows as well as computerization. The empirical evidence presented indicates that globalization has been associated with increasing trade and financial flows to less developed countries. She also notes globalization has also “coincided with increasing penetration of the Internet suggesting that increases in informational flows have complemented economic and financial linkages, but the empirical evidence also shows that the current era of globalization has not been associated with convergence in economic outcomes” (392). She finds that “less‐developed countries have suffered from increases in international income inequality.” (392).                 
In Cypher's "The Process of Economic Development," he writes about the development of ideas of development and looking at the contemporary ones that are influential in development, we find the Solow growth model where total output is a function of technology, capital, and labor, with diminishing returns to capital and labor. In the model, technology comes from outside, and “it is this exogeneous technology which is basic to higher levels of income per capita over time” (150). The model predicts two important things. The first is that there is a steady state equilibrium that can be attained, and that there is a convergence between similar countries. Where there is a ceiling on levels of income per the rate of savings (151), so the model intuits that the way to growth is the increase the savings rate of the nation to raise that ceiling. Or we see the Harrod-Domar growth model. Unlike the Solow model which looked at the savings rate, the Harrod-Domar model sees the rate of growth as a function of both the savings ratio as well as the capital / output ratio (152). Cypher notes that all the theories lead to the same basic idea: “an expansion of total physical capital goods as a share of total output, that is higher levels of investment, that create higher income levels” (153).  One thing about this model is that instead of a steady state, there’s a real chance in the model for instability.
Ultimately, what we want to see is what these models look like when we take them from paper to the real world. Models are necessarily simplifications that exist to concentrate our thought, but what I could not stop thinking when I was reading about the more contemporary models was that the frameworks that are put down are not just simplifications, but something that we could look at and decide if they were true or not. The Solow model is the most attractive because it assumes that if the model is correct, then there are not that many levers we need to be able to pull to make less developed countries meet their peers so that the people in these countries have better lives.
Baddeley’s examination sheds some doubt on the validity of the Solow model. What she finds is that the data does not fully bear out Solow and suggest that something closer to Harrod-Domar is right – the targets are not as easy to hit as suggested, and if you miss them, there are negative consequences: “there has been limited convergence and limited equalization in the distribution of international income and / or that population growth has been too high” (396). The world has become more open, and globalization has allowed technology to be exogenous to other countries in that they have access to technology in unprecedented ways, but there is still a lack of convergence (406-7). Considering findings that trade, and globalization heighten volatility and do not lead to convergence, what do we do? Baddeley suggest that the answer is if we “more carefully regulated and monitored” the financial system as to “moderate the impacts of adverse selection and moral hazard on effective financial decision making” (407). There is a lot of heaving lifting built into that line, as it would include boarder global coordination, an outcome that feels much less likely now than when she was writing.           
For me, if the models are not working, we perhaps need to build new modes of thinking, or to find ones that were once ascendant, but were somehow eclipsed. These neoclassical models are still in people’s heads as their guiding background of how the world is structured and how it works. Since I’ve been in this class, the things I read have taken on development angle, so when I see David Malpass, the current US nominee to lead the World Bank say, “Finally, the bank should also facilitate the adoption of best practices for encouraging broadly shared growth and prosperity. Developing nations can benefit from lessons learnt all over the world. Nations that foster innovation and freer markets, and that have lower taxes, fewer regulatory burdens, and stable currencies, tend to alleviate poverty faster than others. If more countries adopt pro-growth economic environments, the global economy will be stronger” (“What I would do as the next president of the World Bank”), it makes me worry for the future of development strategies as empirical work like Baddeley’s shows we need different strategies because global catchup is happening, and we keep doing the same thing based on outdated frameworks.








Works Cited
Cypher, J. M. (2014). The process of economic development. London: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group.
Malpass, David. “What I Would Do as the next President of the World Bank.” Financial Times, Financial Times, 7 Feb. 2019, www.ft.com/content/ec9a6924-2acb-11e9-9222-7024d72222bc.
Michelle Baddeley (2006) Convergence or Divergence? The Impacts of Globalisation on Growth and Inequality in Less Developed Countries, International Review of Applied Economics, 20:3, 391-410, DOI: 10.1080/02692170600736250

No comments:

Post a Comment